Chapter 5
From Command to Market Economy in
China and Vietnam
Vietnam’s Reforms and
the Chinese Model
Vietnam’s
economic reforms are important in their own right, given that Vietnam is the
thirteenth largest country in the world in terms of population and has proved
to be able to “punch above its weight” in both economic and geopolitical terms.
In the context of this study, however, Vietnam’s recent experience is also a
test of whether the Chinese reform experience was unique to China or was
equally valid elsewhere.
Vietnam began its reforms later and from a different
point from China. Prior to 1986 Vietnam was still trying to implement a
Soviet-type system— specifically, it was trying to impose that system on the
market economy of the southern part of the country after reunification was
achieved in 1975. There were some of what the Vietnamese call “fence-breaking”
reforms in the early 1980s, but for the most part these were the kind of
reforms designed to make the command economy work better, not to replace it
with market forces. Officially the Vietnamese economy grew throughout the
1980s, but the actual performance was poor enough, particularly in agriculture,
that the country experienced serious famine and malnutrition in the winter of
1987– 1988.35 Furthermore, much of the growth actually achieved depended on
large subsidies from the Soviet Union. Vietnam’s imports from 1985 through 1987
rose from US $ 1,590 million to US $ 2,191 million, but the deficit with the
Comecon countries (in effect an explicit or implicit subsidy for the Vietnamese
economy) rose from US $ 721 million in 1985 to US $ 1,276 million in 1987.
The
leader of the post-1975 effort to impose collective agriculture and central
planning on the southern part of the country, Party Secretary General Le Duan,
died in July 1986, but by then many in the Party realized that the efforts of
the past decade had gone badly and needed to change. At the Sixth Party
Congress in December 1986 they elected the reformer Nguyen Van Linh as general
secretary. What really accelerated the need for radical change, however, was
the collapse of Soviet control of eastern Europe in 1989 combined with the
Soviet Union’s own worsening economic conditions and its eventual breakup in
1991. The willingness to continue economic subsidies to Vietnam ended by 1989,
even before the breakup of the Soviet Union. As the data on Vietnam’s trade in
1988 make clear, the end of subsidies meant that Vietnam had to find an
alternative way of paying for 62 percent of its imports. The alternative,
cutting back imports of this magnitude, would have thrown the country into a
deep recession.
For those
familiar with the Vietnam of the twenty-first century, it would be hard to
recognize the country in 1989. When I led a small delegation to Vietnam in
January 1989 to explore whether the Harvard Institute for International
Development could help in making the transition to a more market-oriented
economy, there were very few shops of any kind in Hanoi, and the shelves on
most of them were empty. The situation in the Mekong delta was marginally
better, largely because it was possible to smuggle in goods such as Johnny
Walker Scotch, Kodachrome Film, and motorbikes through Cambodia. The
leadership, however, was clearly ready for fundamental change and had begun to
take steps in that direction. Our host at the time, Foreign Minister Nguyen Co
Thach, had just been reading Samuelson’s textbook Economics in an effort to
learn about how market economies worked. By my next visit a year later the
streets of Hanoi were full of shops, and the goods were flowing out the front
door onto the street. Televisions sets, beer, and numerous other consumer
products from all over Asia were there for purchase if one had the money.
What had
happened was that Vietnam had freed up virtually all prices and removed most
restrictions on imports, and if there were still some restrictions, no one
seemed to be enforcing them. When Vietnam began its transition to a market
economy, however, it had two major problems that were absent in the Chinese
case (although they were also present in the Soviet and eastern European
transitions). The first problem was the one already mentioned: the huge foreign
trade deficit. The second was that the country was suffering from a very high
rate of inflation.
The
solution to the end of Soviet subsidies and the financing of the trade deficit
was partly the result of the reform effort and partly due to luck. As for the
lucky part, Vietnam in a joint venture with the Soviet Vietsovpetro had been
drilling for oil off the coast of Vung Tau in the southern part of Vietnam, and
the wells began producing in 1989, providing Vietnam with several hundred
million dollars of foreign exchange. As for the reform part, the end of the
effort to collectivize agriculture in the south, together with the freeing up
of prices of farm products, led to a boom in rice production, the elimination
of any need for rice imports, and the renewal of Vietnam’s traditional role as
a rice exporter. Oil and rice exports (and the end of rice imports) together
filled roughly two-thirds of the foreign exchange gap in 1989 and 1990. Foreign
aid from the West, Japan, or the World Bank, it should be noted, did not play
any role. Vietnam was still subject to a total embargo with most Western
countries plus Japan, and the World Bank as a result was also not allowed to
lend to the country.
In freeing up prices and opening to foreign trade, Vietnam
did not follow the Chinese dual-price approach of the second half of the 1980s. With the exception of a handful of
energy-related products, all prices were freed up, and all purchasers had to
pay the market price. Vietnam, however, had a major inflation problem that
predated the liberalization of prices. Inflation in 1986– 1988 and before was
running at over 400 percent per year (roughly 14 percent per month). With price
reform and the big increase of goods on the market in 1989– 1991, the rate of
inflation had come down but was still running at 60 percent a year on average.
38 Rates of this magnitude were not consistent with a program designed to
increase the rate of growth of GDP and exports. By 1992, however, the inflation
rate of consumer retail prices had fallen to 17.5 percent, and it fell further
to 5.2 percent in 1993. It stayed down for the rest of the 1990s and well into
the following decade.
The
causes of inflation in Vietnam were similar in important respects to the causes
in China, only more so. Poorly performing state enterprises— most of the
Vietnamese state enterprises in these early reform years— lost their captive
markets at home and abroad and borrowed heavily from the state banking system
to cover their losses. The central bank, as in China, accommodated them by
allowing the money supply to rise rapidly. Solving the inflation problem,
therefore, involved sharp cutbacks in the subsidies, the closing of the worst
performing firms, and cutting back on the excess employment in the firms
remaining. Visiting factories at the time, one often saw many of the workers no
longer on the production line and instead in classrooms learning new skills.
There was no talk of privatizing enterprises in the early 1990s, however, or
much later as well. Vietnam, like China, was still ruled by a Communist Party
that saw state ownership as essential in key areas of the economy.
In some respects the Vietnamese reforms of 1989 and the years
immediately thereafter fit the “big bang” model for reforming a socialist
system minus privatization. Prices, including the exchange rate, were
freed up quickly, inflation was brought under control by sharp cutbacks in
subsidies within less than four years, and the Soviet Comecon system of planned
foreign trade was abolished and Vietnam’s foreign trade system integrated with
the international system, at least that part of the international system that
was not enforcing an embargo on Vietnamese trade. Working with the Vietnamese
government on reform issues at the time, I thought their willingness to rein in
the state enterprise expenditures as vigorously as they did indicated a
willingness to move rapidly and firmly on state enterprise reform more
generally. That did not turn out to be the case. Once inflation was under
control, the state enterprises once again were given a central role in the
government’s development efforts, a role that they still had as of 2012. It is
also possible that the rise of foreign aid after diplomatic normalization with
the United States in 1994 actually slowed down the reform process by making
substantial amounts of foreign exchange available without taking further steps
to reform the state enterprises.
Vietnam
also moved dramatically to end collectivization of agriculture in the north and
to end efforts to implement it in the south. The 1988 land law effectively
returned ownership of arable land to the household, although there were debates
at the time as to just who would get the land— specifically whether there would
be some further redistribution to reward those who had fought for the
revolution. In addition, the farmers got only land use rights, not outright
ownership, and these rights were to expire after 20 years. Rice land, in most
cases, continued to have an obligation to grow rice. The return to family-owned
farms led to an immediate jump in rice output that restored Vietnam’s role as a
rice exporter after years of importing rice. Agricultural reform combined with
price reform led to a boom in higher valued agricultural crops such as coffee,
fruits, rubber, and farmed fish, all of which, together with rice exports, made
major contributions to solving the country’s balance-of-payments problems as
well as raising the incomes of farmers.
Even
before inflation was under full control, the performance of the Vietnamese
economy and the development model it pursued looked more and more like the
Chinese model. The GDP growth rate in 1989 was only 4.7 percent, or 3 percent
per capita, but the average per capita growth rate throughout the 1990s was 5.9
percent per year. Exports grew slowly in the early 1990s, but with the ending
of the U.S. embargo in early 1994 (and many other countries ended it earlier),
Vietnamese exports took off. From 1994 through the year 2000 exports grew at 25
percent per year, passing US $ 14 billion in 2000. The content of Vietnam’s
exports was both similar and different from that of China’s during the first
decade of reform. Consumer manufactures, notably shoes, accounted for one-third
of Vietnam’s exports during the 1990s, but minerals, mostly petroleum,
accounted for more than a quarter of the total, with agricultural and aquatic
products (rice, coffee, shrimp. etc.) making up much of the rest— not the case
in China. Manufactured exports in China, in contrast, accounted for two-thirds
of exports in the latter half of the 1980s. Vietnam, partly because it was in
the tropics and partly because its per capita income was lower than that of
China, had larger surpluses of agricultural products that could be sold abroad.
By the
end of the first decade of the twenty-first century, Vietnam’s economic model
looked much the same as it did in the late 1990s. From the end of the 1990s,
GDP continued to grow through 2007 at an average rate of 7.6 percent a year,
actually accelerating to over 8 percent a year in 2005– 2007. Exports in
nominal terms also continued to grow rapidly at 19.7 percent a year from the
beginning of 2000 through 2007, but the structure of exports did not change
much from the 1990s. The dominant exports continued to be shoes, textiles, and
garments, with some increase in the assembly of electronic products, all mostly
produced by foreign direct investment firms, plus petroleum, coffee, rice, and
other agricultural and fishery products. In China in the 1990s exports came
increasingly from heavy industry products such as machinery and transport
equipment, but in Vietnam heavy industries, other than petroleum, continued to
produce at high cost behind high protective barriers, including favored access
to land and credit and favored interpretations or noninterpretations of law.
The major
policy change in the first part of the post-2000 decade was the passage of laws
(the Enterprise Laws of 2000 and 2005) that legitimized domestic private business,
providing security for Vietnamese investors in that sector comparable to what
foreign investors in Vietnam already received. Prior to these laws, private
industry above household size was virtually nonexistent, although there were a
few private industrial firms, disguised under other ownership categories. After
the passage of the Enterprise Laws, the private sector boomed. Private industry
in 2006– 2010 grew at an average annual rate of 21.6 percent per year, even
faster than the 16.6 percent annual growth rate of foreign direct investment
industry. Both sectors slowed down at the height of the global financial crisis
in 2009 but then bounced back in 2010.
State-owned industry did not fare anywhere near as well, growing at an average
annual rate of 8.7 percent in 2006– 2010. A number of the major state
industrial enterprises began to spread out into businesses unrelated to their
main activity, notably into real estate speculation. Vinashin, the state
shipbuilding company, was the most notorious, raising roughly US $ 1 billion
from foreign sources in 2007 and then investing the money in speculative
activities, most of which had little to do with building ships and which
performed badly, effectively forcing the government to bail out the company.
But Vinashin was not alone. As in China in the 1980s and 1990s, there was a
close relationship between the large state enterprises, the state banks, and
the leadership of the Communist Party. Many of these state enterprises borrowed
heavily from the state banks and then used the money on real estate projects
and other speculative activity unrelated to their core businesses. The large
increases in the money supply that resulted from this profligate borrowing
began to show up in consumer prices. Whereas the average rate of increase in
the consumer price index starting in 2001 and carrying through 2007 was 5.6
percent per year, in 2008 the rate jumped to 23 percent, fell to 6.9 percent
during the global financial crisis in 2009, and then rose to 9.2 percent in
2010 and 18.6 percent in 2011 and back to 9.2 percent in 2012. The nominal
exchange rate rose much more slowly than inflation, resulting in an overvalued
exchange rate and a sharp fall in Vietnam’s foreign exchange reserves in 2011.
Vietnam
in the latter half of the first 12 years of the twenty-first century had more
in common with China in the early 1990s than with China in the latter half of
that decade. As this chapter is being written, there is no evidence that anyone
comparable to Zhu Rongji is going to take command in Vietnam, rein in bank
lending, and force the state industrial enterprises to face international
competition. Vietnam’s GDP growth rate has fallen from 8 percent per year in
2005– 2007 to 5.9 percent per year in 2008– 2012, a respectable rate by global
developing country standards but far below China’s rate during the same years.
The global financial crisis is partly to blame for this slowdown, but stalled
economic reforms are clearly also part of the story.
By 2010,
both Vietnam and China’s economies had moved a long way from the prereform
period, and in key structural ways their economies had much in common with
those of South Korea and Taiwan in the 1970s and 1980s. But it would be a
mistake to describe what happened in China or Vietnam as a decision by the
Chinese and Vietnamese leadership to abandon the Soviet model of growth and
switch to the model of South Korea or Japan.
To begin
with China: as Deng Xiaoping said, China’s reforms were like a person crossing
a river feeling for the stones. China had no clear model that it followed from
the outset. Instead it faced a series of problems and tried to solve them one
by one. The first problem was the need to take full advantage of the superior
technologies available abroad instead of trying to reinvent the wheel within in
China. That step required foreign exchange, and after decades of neglecting
foreign trade China didn’t have much foreign exchange— hence the decision to
accelerate the growth of exports. Since China couldn’t afford to squeeze food consumption
further and the country was not rich in natural resources (and offshore oil
finds initially were disappointing), exporting manufactures was the only
alternative.
In these
early years of reform, China also faced a severe poverty problem, mainly in the
countryside, and the solution chosen to achieve a sharp reduction in poverty
was to abandon the commune experiment and return to household farming. The
immediate result was a large jump in farm output, but after 1984 China reverted
to much slower agricultural growth and a rapidly declining share of agriculture
in GDP. Better incentives could remove many of the inefficiencies of the
commune system, but they could not overcome the fact that China had very little
arable land per capita (0.6 hectares per rural family or 0.15 hectares per
rural person), 39 and the yields on that land were often already comparable to
the highest yields elsewhere in the world.
The next
problem was how to accelerate the growth of industry so that China did not
continue to fall further behind its neighbors both in per capita income and in
industrial technology terms. The initial focus was on trying to make the
state-owned enterprises perform better, and a wide variety of measures were
tried, none of which was particularly successful. But one of the measures
tried, making industrial inputs available on the market at market prices, had a
surprising side effect. The townships and villages outside the large cities
experienced a boom, as local manufacturers and entrepreneurs could now get the
inputs they needed, and township and village enterprises boomed and carried the
entire economy with them.
The
tragedy of June 4, 1989, temporarily derailed this step-by-step movement across
the river and threatened a return to a more state-directed economy, but Deng
Xiaoping reversed that retreat with his southern tour in 1992. It is hard to
imagine the success achieved by China’s reforms in the absence of Deng
Xiaoping. Given the politics and ideologically driven programs of the prereform
era, China could have gone down a very different path of state-controlled and
state-directed slower growth possibly for decades before running into the
massive inefficiencies of such an approach as the economy became more and more
complex. But Deng Xiaoping was there and he did endorse continued reform, and
so the step-by-step approach resumed.
In the
1990s the drag of the weak performance of the state-owned enterprises was
causing a variety of connected problems that threatened overall economic
performance. The close relationship between the state industrial enterprises
and the state banks was leading the banks down a path to insolvency as
nonperforming loans piled up. The ease with which state enterprises could get
state bank loans also led to accelerating inflation that was a threat to
political stability. So China’s leaders took the dramatic but highly practical
step of forcing the state enterprises to reform or go out of business. They did
this by joining the WTO and making it difficult for the state to continue to
give the kind of support to state enterprises that had been the norm in the
past. In this respect, China was quite different from South Korea, Taiwan, and
Japan. China has steadily moved toward a trading system that is open on both
the import and the export side, with the notable exception in recent years of
the undervalued exchange rate. And China has promoted foreign direct
investment. Japan, South Korea prior to 1998, and Taiwan, in contrast, tightly
restricted foreign direct investment and during the first decades of their high
growth implemented high tariff and nontariff barriers to imports.
Thus
China ended up in a place similar, although far from identical, to that of its
East Asian neighbors. China had no doubt learned from their experience but had
got to where it was in 2000 by its own path and in its own way. This way has
sometimes been described as a gradual approach to development in contrast to
the “big bang” radical transformations instituted in eastern Europe and many of
the states of the former Soviet Union. Some of China’s reforms were certainly
gradual. It took two decades before China faced up to the need to do something
dramatic and effective vis-à-vis the state-owned enterprises. On the other hand
the rural reforms were carried out over a period of only a few years, and the
opening of the economy to foreign trade occurred quickly as well. Where all
that was involved was getting rid of an institution that did not work well (the
rural communes for example) one could move quickly. Where new institutions and
attitudes had to be created, moving quickly was never possible. Moving quickly
was also not possible because China’s goal was a very general one, to become
wealthy and powerful, but the country had been struggling with how to do that
since the nineteenth century. Implementing such a general goal involved far
more difficult choices than reform in Poland and elsewhere in eastern and
central Europe in the early 1990s, where the goal of many of the countries was
to join the European Union and become as much like the existing EU countries as
fast as possible.
The
Vietnam economic reform story from 1989 on has much in common with the Chinese
story and hence with the experiences of South Korea and Taiwan, and Vietnam
went down a similar route for many of the same reasons that China, South Korea,
and Taiwan did. Some years ago a senior member of Vietnam’s Politburo whom I
had gotten to know criticized an essay I had written in which I suggested that
Vietnam’s economic reform path was patterned on that of China. As he rightly
pointed out and this chapter has attempted to show, the economic reform process in Vietnam as well as China
was driven by the economic and political context in which reform decisions were
made. The leaders of Vietnam certainly knew about and learned from the
reform experiences of China that preceded their reform effort. As one senior
Vietnamese official said to me after one of my many lectures there on China’s
reforms, “we are always interested in hearing what China’s is
doing because we know that we will soon be facing many of the same problems
they are dealing with.”
When it
came to the decision to open up the economy to trade with market economies, for
example, Vietnam’s initial problem was that they had to deal with a loss of
Soviet subsidies and Comecon markets together with high inflation, problems
that China did not have in the late 1970s. The beginning of production of the
Bach Ho (White Tiger) oil field solved part of the first problem, and the 1988
land law that involved the abandonment of collectivization of agriculture also
helped solve the balance-of-payments deficit. Thus Vietnam was able to meet its
foreign exchange needs initially with exports of petroleum and a restoration of
its traditional rice-exporting status. China, in contrast, given the limited
success of its oil exploration efforts, had little choice other than to promote
the rapid expansion of labor-intensive manufactured exports where it already
had experience. The partial shift in emphasis to manufactured exports came
about later in Vietnam, in part because of the embargo that was still in place
in the early 1990s and in part because by the mid-1990s Hong Kong, Korean, and
Taiwanese manufacturers of shoes and textiles were looking for production
platforms that would diversify their businesses so as to escape from
overdependence on China.
When it came to the speed of reform, both China and Vietnam
moved quickly to abandon collectivization, although the approach of China was
bottom up and took several years, while that of Vietnam was more top down and
was completed more quickly, in part because collectivization had never taken
hold in the Vietnamese south, whereas all of China had been collectivized for
over two decades. Vietnam’s decision to deal decisively at the outset with closing
inefficient state-owned enterprises was driven mainly by the need to rein in
rapid inflation, and the effort slowed as soon as inflation was under control.
The fact that state enterprises in Vietnam were a smaller share of the economy
may have made it politically easier for the leadership to avoid halfway reform
measures like China’s dual-price system in the latter half of the 1980s.
China’s initial efforts to reform state owned enterprises were quite modest
throughout the 1980s, and reform was further set back after June 4, 1989. What
changed in 1992 was Deng Xiaoping’s personal decision to use his status and
power to force the restoration of the reform effort, followed by Zhu Rongji’s
determined leadership to force state enterprises to become internationally
competitive in the late 1990s. There has been no comparable political effort in
Vietnam vis-à-vis state-owned enterprises, and they continue to operate as
import-substituting firms behind government protective barriers. The
failure to further reform Vietnam’s state-owned enterprises is probably one of
the reasons why China’s GDP growth rate has averaged over 9 percent per year
while that of Vietnam has risen at 7 percent a year during the 23-year reform
period and less than 6 percent per year during the most recent five years
ending in 2012.
The
decisions made by China and Vietnam, therefore, reflected their specific
contexts, but the many similarities in their reforms derived in part, though
only in part, from the fact that both were moving away from similar failed
Soviet-style command economies. The fact that China started a full decade ahead
of Vietnam also meant that Vietnam had a model to learn from and follow where
appropriate. In addition, these two economies both ended up with development
strategies that in key respects looked much like those pursued by Japan, South
Korea, and Taiwan. The decision to turn outward with respect to reliance on
foreign trade and the export of manufactures was common to all of these
economies. In all five economies the government played an active role in
directing economic activity, especially during the first decades of reform and
rapid growth. All of these economies had major government programs to promote
heavy industries. Japan and to a large degree South Korea relied on private
firms to carry out these plans whereas China, Vietnam, and Taiwan (in the early
phase of the program) relied more on state-owned enterprises, but the direction
came from government. Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan used higher tariffs,
quantitative restrictions, and undervalued exchange rates to limit imports that
would compete with domestic producers, whereas China mainly used an undervalued
exchange rate; but that difference reflected the terms China had to accept to
become a member of the WTO, whereas Japan and South Korea were already members
and started their reforms in an era when the United States was much more
tolerant of developing country trade restrictions. Vietnam has not deliberately
tried to keep its exchange rate undervalued, and that may reflect in part its
greater reliance on the export of natural resource commodities as opposed to
manufactures.
Overall,
the fact that all of these economies relied on active government intervention
to promote industrialization and economic growth probably reflects, in part,
the fact that all had large, well-organized bureaucracies staffed with
relatively well-educated personnel who had the capacity to make government
intervention in the economy work with a reasonable level of efficiency. It is
not entirely clear where this organizational capacity came from. In China it
was probably a combination of centuries of experience with the bureaucratic
rule of the Confucian governmental system, the Communist Party’s own experience
over two decades of managing a complex war and revolution against both the
Japanese and the Guomindang, and an increasingly well-educated population. In
Vietnam, French colonial rule eliminated any substantial personal experience
among the Vietnamese with managing a bureaucracy, but they had 30 years of
successfully managing a revolutionary war involving the mobilization and supply
of millions of troops, the constant need to repair infrastructure destroyed by
bombing, and much else. And the fact that they managed this against the French,
the Americans, and the South Vietnamese Government created considerable
organizational capacity. No such government capacity existed in most of
Southeast Asia outside Vietnam.
The major differences between the development strategies of
these economies, as contrasted to their similarities, include the fact that China
and Vietnam welcomed large-scale foreign direct investment while Japan, South
Korea, and Taiwan did not. All of these economies at the beginning of the second decade of
the twenty-first century, however, are part of the complex multicountry supply
chains that characterize most manufacturing in the region today. One suspects
that the hostility to foreign direct investment in the three earlier developers
was more a product of politics and culture than anything else. Japanese
business practices and business-government relations have never been
accommodating to the inclusion of outsiders. In South Korea, in addition to
strong nationalist feelings, there was the fear that opening up to foreign
direct investment would lead to renewed Japanese control of Korean businesses.
China’s leaders, in contrast, seemed to worry little about their ability to
control the activities of foreign investors. Somewhat like Koreans, many
Vietnamese worry about the ability to control Chinese foreign direct investment
in their country but not investment from elsewhere. In fact, involving foreign
investment in offshore oil exploration is seen by the Vietnamese as a way to
protect themselves against what they perceive as Chinese encroachment.
In broad
terms, the factor endowment of these five economies is similar, so it is not
surprising that their development strategies have been similar. All had limited
endowments of arable land relative to the size of their population, and all,
except Vietnam, were in the temperate zone. None had plentiful nonagricultural
natural resources relative to the size of its population. All had a Confucian
heritage that generated a strong desire for education, backed up by a premodern
base of education that was readily expanded into a modern mass education program,
resulting in increasingly well-educated labor forces. All five started with
governments led by individuals mostly talented at making war and revolution but
then made the transition to leaders devoted to modernizing their economies. The
main difference in the timing of the rapid growth period of each country had to
do with when the emphasis on war and revolution gave way to the emphasis on
development. It happened first in Japan with defeat in World War II, moved on
to Taiwan and South Korea in the early 1960s, where survival depended on
successful economic development, and then to China in the late 1970s and
Vietnam in the late 1980s, when revolutionary leaders gave way to leaders who
wanted to make their countries wealthy and powerful. These leaders not only
wanted to implement development programs that would achieve these goals but
also led governments that had the capacity to carry out interventionist
policies without excessive political and rent-seeking distortions.
Finally there is the question of whether or how the nature
of the political systems in Northeast and Southeast Asia shaped the development
strategies pursued, and what the experience of those East Asian economies that
have achieved high-income status implies for China and Vietnam. Full treatment
of this subject would require a separate book, but a few generalizations are
possible from the analysis in this and previous chapters. All of the rapidly
growing economies of Northeast and Southeast Asia began with authoritarian
political systems, with the possible exceptions of Singapore and Malaysia,
where votes were honestly counted in elections and there were opposition
candidates, although the playing field was not an even one. Some of these
authoritarian governments managed highly effective development policies while
others oversaw economic disasters. In the case of South Korea and Taiwan,
external threats to the very existence of their economic and political systems
kept governments focused on following economic policies that worked and dropping
those that did not. Potential external threats of a somewhat different kind
also played a role in Singapore.
External
threats, however, had little to do with why the governments of China and
Vietnam were able to stay focused on effective development policies. The key
change in both China and Vietnam was the transition from a generation of
leaders mostly skilled at making revolution and fighting wars to leaders who
were mainly concerned with making their countries wealthy and powerful. In
Vietnam’s case, the end of subsidies from its powerful ally the Soviet Union
was a further impetus. The changeover from a revolutionary leader to the next
generation is also part of the explanation for Indonesia’s relative success,
but authoritarian rule under President Suharto had a mixed development record.
It was effective during periods such as the late 1960s and the 1980s when major
economic crises in the immediate past kept the ablest technocrats in control,
but poor policies led to crises in the mid-1970s and the 1990s, when prior
success bred hubris on the part of senior politicians. In the Philippines,
authoritarian rule by President Marcos was an unmitigated disaster.
Did the transition to democracy in several of these
countries change policies, were the changes positive or negative for economic
growth, and are there any implications for China and Vietnam in the experience
of the countries that made this transition? In South Korea and Taiwan,
democracy coincided with a shift away from a high level of government intervention
in the economy to greater reliance on market forces, but that transition began
before the change in the political systems and reflected more the requirements
of increasingly sophisticated and open economies. The slowdown in growth in
South Korea and Taiwan, as will be seen in Chapter 6, had nothing to do with
the transition to democracy.
The transition to democracy in
Indonesia has been accompanied by fairly high GDP growth, but that is mostly
due to high international prices for natural resource exports, not a coherent
and effective government development strategy. The transition back to democracy
in the Philippines has led to improvements over the Marcos years, but not
dramatic improvements. In Malaysia, democracy— arguably in place since independence—
has brought political stability to the country that has helped growth, but
stability was bought in part with policies strongly favoring one ethnic group
that have inhibited economic growth. If there are any lessons for China and
Vietnam’s approach to development in this recent political history, it is not
clear what they are. The one certainty is that China and Vietnam will have to
find more and more ways to accommodate the demands of an increasingly
prosperous and well-educated population, but how this will impact their
development strategies remains to be seen.
Next I
shall explore whether the similarities in economic structure and reform
strategies continued in East Asia as the high-growth spurt in some of the
economies reached its end. For the countries of Southeast Asia, including
Vietnam but excluding Singapore, this end-of-high-growth story is some way off,
but in Northeast Asia it has already arrived. In China, however, high growth
has been sustained in an economy with an increasingly unusual economic
structure.
Source: Perkins, Dwight H. (2013-10-21).
East Asian Development (The Edwin O. Reischauer lectures) (Kindle Locations
2516-2779). Harvard University Press. Kindle Edition.
Không có nhận xét nào:
Đăng nhận xét